Draft:Rational bubble

Rational bubble is a theoretical framework in economics to model speculative bubble, a situation in which the asset price exceeds the fundamental value defined by the present discounted value of future dividends of the asset. The qualifier "rational" refers to the fact that investors are willing to purchase the overpriced asset despite holding rational expectations, although common beliefs and information among investors are also implicitly assumed.

Definition

[edit]

For simplicity, we define rational bubbles in a deterministic setting.[1]

Consider an infinite-horizon, deterministic economy with a homogeneous good and time indexed by . Consider an asset with infinite maturity that pays dividend and trades at ex-dividend price , both in units of the time- good. In the background, we assume the presence of rational, perfectly competitive investors. Let be the Arrow-Debreu price, that is, the date-0 price of the consumption good delivered at time , with the normalization . The absence of arbitrage implies

Iterating forward and using , we obtain

Because and , the sequence is increasing in and bounded above by . Therefore, by the monotone convergence theorem, the sequence converges and the infinite sum of the present value of dividends

exists, which is called the fundamental value of the asset. Letting in the above summation, we obtain

where is the bubble component. When , we say that the no-bubble condition[2] holds, in which case we obtain and the asset price equals its fundamental value. If

then and we say that the asset contains a (rational) bubble.

Interpretation

[edit]

Because free disposal forces the asset price to be nonnegative (), the limit is always nonnegative. Therefore, , so there can never be a "negative bubble".

The economic meaning of the bubble component is that it captures a speculative aspect, that is, investors buy the asset now for the purpose of resale in the future, rather than (in addition to) for the purpose of receiving dividends.[3]

Bubble Characterization Lemma

[edit]

The following Bubble Characterization Lemma due to Montrucchio[4][5] is useful for determining the existence of bubbles.

Bubble Characterization LemmaIf for all , the asset price exhibits a bubble if and only if .

Proof

Changing time from to in the no-arbitrage condition yields

Dividing both sides by yields

Multiplying from to yields

Expanding terms and applying the inequality yields

Letting , it follows that if and only if .

The Bubble Characterization Lemma states that there is a bubble if and only if future dividend yields are summable. In other words, the price-dividend ratio must grow sufficiently fast.

Example

[edit]

The following example is perhaps the simplest example of a rational bubble attached to dividend-paying assets.[6]

Consider a two-period overlapping generations model with Cobb Douglas utility

where are consumption of generation when young and old. Assume generation has endowment when young but nothing when old. Suppose the initial old are endowed with a dividend-paying asset in unit supply. Let be the price and dividend of the asset at time .

Letting be the asset holdings of the young at time , the budget constraints of generation are

Solving the utility maximization problem yields . Using the market clearing condition yields the asset price

The dividend yield is therefore

Consequently, by the Bubble Characterization Lemma, we obtain the following result.

PropositionIn this overlapping generations model, there is a rational bubble if and only if .

Notable works

[edit]

The 1958 paper of Samuelson[7] that introduced money in the overlapping generations model is generally considered to be the first example of a rational bubble model (with a zero-dividend asset (money), which is often called a pure bubble). Bewley (1980) constructed a rational bubble model with infinitely-lived agents.[8] Tirole (1985) showed that the emergence of a bubble resolves capital overaccumulation (dynamic inefficiency).[9] Kocherlakota (1992) showed that whenever a bubble arises, the present value of the aggregate endowment is infinite.[10] Santos and Woodford (1997) showed that when dividends comprise a non-negligile fraction of the aggregate endowment, then bubbles are impossible.[11] Hirano and Toda (2025a) proved that when the dividend growth rate exceeds the natural interest rate but is lower than the economic growth rate (perhaps due to unbalanced growth between different sectors),[12] then bubbles inevitably emerge.[13]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ Hirano & Toda 2024, Section 2.
  2. ^ Giglio, Stefano; Maggiori, Matteo; Stroebel, Johannes (2016). "No-Bubble Condition: Model-Free Tests in Housing Markets". Econometrica. 84 (3): 1047–1091. doi:10.3982/ECTA13447.
  3. ^ Hirano & Toda 2025b, p. 6.
  4. ^ Montrucchio 2004, Proposition 7.
  5. ^ Hirano & Toda 2025a, Lemma1.
  6. ^ Hirano & Toda 2025a, Section III.A.
  7. ^ Samuelson, Paul A. (December 1958). "An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest with or without the Social Contrivance of Money". Journal of Political Economy. 66 (6): 467–482. doi:10.1086/258100.
  8. ^ Bewley, Truman (1980). "The Optimum Quantity of Money". In Kareken, John H.; Wallace, Neil (eds.). Models of Monetary Economies. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. pp. 169–210.
  9. ^ Tirole, Jean (1985). "Asset Bubbles and Overlapping Generations". Econometrica. 53 (6): 1499–1528. doi:10.2307/1913232. JSTOR 1913232.
  10. ^ Kocherlakota, Narayana R. (1992). "Bubbles and constraints on debt accumulation". Journal of Economic Theory. 57 (1): 245–256. doi:10.1016/S0022-0531(05)80052-3.
  11. ^ Santos, Manuel S.; Woodford, Michael (1997). "Rational Asset Pricing Bubbles". Econometrica. 65 (1): 19-57. doi:10.2307/2171812. JSTOR 2171812.
  12. ^ Hirano, Tomohiro; Toda, Alexis Akira (2025). "Unbalanced growth and land overvaluation". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 122 (14) e2423295122. arXiv:2307.00349. Bibcode:2025PNAS..12223295H. doi:10.1073/pnas.2423295122. PMC 12002243. PMID 40178889.
  13. ^ Hirano & Toda 2025a, Theorem 2 and Section V.

References

[edit]