Demurrage currency
Demurrage currency,[a] also known as shrinking or depreciating money,[2]: 7 is a type of money that is designed to gradually lose purchasing power at a flat constant rate.[b] Unlike traditional money, demurrage is designed to only be a temporary store of value. Demurrage money functions primarily as a medium of exchange and unit of account.[3][2]: 16 In some cases, demurrage currencies have been employed as emergency currencies, intended to keep the circular flow of income running throughout the economy during recessions and times of war, due to their faster circulation velocities.[2]: 16–17
Demurrage is sometimes cited as economically advantageous, usually in the context of complementary currency systems. The German-Argentine economist, Silvio Gesell, advocated for demurrage currency as part of the Freiwirtschaft economic system. He referred to demurrage as Freigeld 'free money'. Gesell theorized that Freigeld would lead to fewer recessions by increasing the velocity of money, eliminating inflation, and creating an interest-free economy.[3]
Theory
[edit]The functions of money
[edit]While demurrage carrying costs[b] are a natural feature of commodity money, demurrage has at various times been deliberately incorporated into currency systems as a disincentive to hoard money and to achieve more efficient allocation of capital in society, thus creating demurrage currency.
Freiwirtschaft economists propose that the function of money as a store of value is incompatible with its function as a medium of exchange for maximum economic efficiency. In The Natural Economic Order, Gesell wrote: "The power of money to effect exchanges, its technical quality from the mercantile standpoint, is in inverse proportion to its technical quality from the banking standpoint."[4] This implies that money that is great for storing wealth, such as hard currency, is bad for functioning as a medium of exchange, which is the primary reason why money was created in the first place. Since demurrage currency is deliberately designed to be bad at storing value, it is therefore great at functioning as a medium of exchange,[5] which Gesell believed to be the only legitimate function of money.[6][7]
“Only money that goes out of date like a newspaper, rots like potatoes, rusts like iron, evaporates like ether, is capable of standing the test as an instrument for the exchange of potatoes, newspapers, iron and ether. For such money is not preferred to goods either by the purchaser or the seller. We then part with our goods for money only because we need the money as a means of exchange, not because we expect an advantage from possession of the money. So we must make money worse as a commodity if we wish to make it better as a medium of exchange."[5]
— Silvio Gesell, The Natural Economic Order
Gresham's law that "bad money drives out good" suggests that demurrage currency would suffer more rapid circulation than competing forms of currency. This led some such as Silvio Gesell to propose demurrage as a means of increasing both the velocity of money and overall economic activity. In real-life experiments during the early-to-mid 1900s, demurrage on money was demonstrated to significantly increase the velocity of money in circulation, even incentivizing people to pay their taxes in advance.[8]
Preventing recessions
[edit]One of the most important differences between demurrage and inflation is how they affect economic recessions differently:[9]
- Inflation is defined as "a general rise in prices".
- During recessions, prices tend to fall.
- When prices fall and we can expect them to continue falling, commerce falls too. People avoid buying commodities sooner when they expect that they can buy them cheaper later.
- Recessions thus face a game theory problem: society wants to increase commerce, but nobody with hoardable money wants to increase commerce if prices will continue to fall.
- If prices are falling, then there is no inflation, by definition.
- If there is no inflation, then there are no penalties for withholding money from circulation during a recession.
- Thus, holders of money are rewarded for withholding their money from circulation during periods of falling prices.
- This makes it difficult to increase circulation and end the recession.
By contrast, demurrage currency would encourage people to keep commerce going during recessions, unlike inflation. If money continues to lose purchasing power (even at a slow rate), then people will use it sooner rather than later.[10]
In some cases, demurrage currencies have been employed as emergency currencies, intended to keep the circular flow of income running throughout the economy during recessions and times of war, due to their faster circulation velocities.[2]: 16–17
Other differences between demurrage and inflation
[edit]Both inflation and demurrage reduce the purchasing power of money held over time, but there are many differences between the two. Unlike inflation, demurrage gradually reduces only the value of currency held, not on newly issued money, money placed into a bank (from the lender's perspective), or money that will be issued in the future. By contrast, inflation also reduces the value of savings, retirement funds, while increasing prices across the consumer price index.
Inflation also benefits borrowers at the expense of lenders, whereas demurrage does not. The effect of demurrage on borrowers depends on what they do with the money. If they spend it (either for consumption or investment), they do not bear the cost of demurrage. If borrowers hold onto the money, they would lose due to demurrage. Hence, people would be strongly disincentivized to borrow money without spending it.
The rate of inflation usually fluctuates, and inflation may devalue currency in a variety of ways, so inflation is not easy to predict.[11][12] By contrast, the depreciation rate of demurrage currency would stay at a fixed rate set by the government, thus leading to a more stable and predictable economy.
Interest rates, lending, and borrowing
[edit]Some regard demurrage as a negative interest rate policy, but they have different effects. Under demurrage currency, hoarding money becomes impossible because the face-value of money depreciates regularly. This forces the circulation of money.[13] By contrast, it is possible to hoard money on negative interests, since the face-value of money is constant and people can use their money as a means of saving. For example, Japan's negative interest rates drove up the sales of safes and strongboxes.[14]
If the liquidity preference theory of interest rates is correct, then interest rates would disappear if money cannot be used as a long-term store of value. Since demurrage currency would automatically lose value over time, there would be no incentive to store or hoard it. Banks would instead be incentivized to loan money in order to avoid paying demurrage fees. Bankers would therefore have incentives to lend demurrage money without charging interest rates, in order to reduce the disincentives for borrowers to borrow demurrage money.[15][3] The result would be an interest-free economy.
Borrowers would also be incentivized to use the demurrage money as soon as possible before the purchasing power decreases due to demurrage. Since demurrage money would theoretically increase the velocity of money, eliminate interest rates, and lower the opportunity costs to borrowing credit, demurrage money would theoretically lead to greater economic efficiency and prosperity.[16]
For long-term investment financing, demurrage currency affects the dynamics of net present value (NPV) calculations. Demurrage in a currency system reduces discount rates, and thus increases the present value of a long-term investment, and thus gives an incentive for such investments.[17]
Freiwirtschaft economist Felix Fuders argues that the growth imperative of modern economies is caused by interest burdens on debt, inflation, and interest as opportunity costs.[18] Fuders believes that the growth imperative has harmful environmental, mental, and social consequences.[19] Fuders concludes that it is impossible to meaningfully address the problem of unsustainable growth or fulfill the sustainable development goals proposed by the United Nations without completely overhauling the monetary system in favor of demurrage currency.[20]
Proceeds of the system
[edit]In some instances, the demurrage fee is charged by some sort of central authority, and is paid into a fund. The application of this fund varies widely among both historical and proposed systems. In some cases, it is used to pay the costs of administering the tax. If the currency in question is run by the government, the demurrage fee can contribute to general tax revenue.
In Gesell's proposed system, the individual owners of Freigeld would pay the demurrage fee for the stamps to the government, thus reducing the amount of other taxes that a government would have to collect.[15] If individuals don't want to pay the demurrage fees, they could deposit their money into a bank. The bank would become responsible for paying for the stamp fees, and the money would retain its full value from the depositor's perspective. Bank would thus be incentivized to loan the money in order to pass the holding expense onto others and avoid paying for the stamps, which would guarantee that plenty of money would be available for lending in the economy. Gesell believed that banks would loan until their interest rates eventually fall to zero. Banks would collect only a small risk premium and an administration fee, without any need to adjust for inflation or deflation.[15]
In mutual credit systems, all positive accounts, or those over a credit threshold, are debited the demurrage fee if there is no trading (purchasing) after a certain period (e.g. a month or year after the last purchase). Typically the fee accrues to the administration account and thus adds to the common credit pool.
Critical Analysis
[edit]British economist John Maynard Keynes contended that Gesell's proposed demurrage fees could be evaded by the use of more liquid competing forms of money and that therefore inflation was a preferable method to achieve economic stimulation.[21]
According to economist Dirk Löhr , while demurrage currency has successfully worked on local scales in the past and present, and while freiland reform is possible without freigeld reform, there is an economic consensus that successful large-scale freigeld monetary reform will not be possible without freiland reform.[22] The reason is that if money can no longer be used as a long-term store of wealth, then most people would shift to storing their wealth within land instead. If land reform is unfeasible for any reason, then large scale freigeld reform will be unlikely to have its intended effects.
Professors Nikolaus Läufer and Gerhard Rösl argued that demurrage currencies can only increase economic activity temporarily.[23] They believe that although the velocity of money would increase in the short-term, the total amount in circulation would gradually decrease, since demurrage currencies lose value over time. The lengthy use of demurrage currencies would thus ultimately lead to a decline in economic activity and economic instability.[24][clarification needed] However, Gesell supported allowing a monetary authority to monitor the money supply. If the amount of money in circulation falls too much, the monetary authorty would print more money.[15]
Gesell believed that Freiwirtschaft would create Darwinian natural selection in the economy: "Free competition would favor the efficient and lead to their increased propagation."[15] Marxists such as the academic Elmar Altvater described Freigeld as a "Social Darwinist concept" and criticized its past supporters for trying to ally with the Nazi Party, even though the Nazis ignored their ideas.[25] Werner Onken replied to this accusation that the theory of evolution was new at that time and existed in contrast to the dogmas of Christianity above all. Onken wrote that Gesell did not represent a "struggle of the strongest against the weaker", as he instead advocated "to create the conditions for a just distribution of income and wealth".[26]
History
[edit]Pre-modern usage
[edit]Bernard Lietaer documents in his book Mysterium Geld the use of demurrage currency systems in Europe's High Middle Ages' bracteate systems and Ancient Egypt's ostraka – dated receipts for the storage of grain – and credits these currency systems with the prosperity of those societies.[27] One notable example of demurrage is the founder of the Mark of Brandenburg, Albert the Bear.[28]
The Islamic system of zakat sometimes works as a form of demurrage tax, but not always since it applies to assets generally, not currency specifically. Zakat on wealth is based on the value of all of one's possessions.[29][30] It is customarily 2.5% (or 1⁄40)[31] of a Muslim's total savings and wealth above a minimum amount known as nisab each lunar year,[32] but Islamic scholars differ on how much nisab is and other aspects of zakat.[32] Today, in most Muslim-majority countries, zakat contributions are voluntary, while in Libya, Malaysia, Pakistan, Saudi Arabia, Sudan and Yemen, zakat is mandated and collected by the state (as of 2015).[33][34]
Guernsey experiment of 1815
[edit]In 1815, there was a money experiment on Guernsey in the British Channel Islands. The consequences of the Napoleonic Wars were noticeable throughout Europe, including on this island. The islanders produced food far beyond its own needs, but the collected taxes and interest payments to London banks finally brought payments to a halt. The incumbent governor of Guernsey, Daniel de Lisle Brock, proposed the construction of a market hall for 4000 pounds sterling to give the economy a new impetus. These 4000 pounds were printed and put into circulation as a kind of second currency. After five years, the hall had fully amortized, which means that it had fully earned its depreciation and the 4000 pounds, which had now been in circulation on the whole of the island and had caused all kinds of revenues, were again available to the investor of the market hall, and were no longer needed and burned. According to this principle, several building projects with self-printed and later again destroyed building projects were realized one after the other. However, by 1835, the intervention of foreign banks and a reduced money supply caused the economy to come to a standstill again. Some supporters of Freiwirtschaft, including Hermann Benjes , regard the "Mirakel of Guernsey" as a precursor to demurrage money,[35] after Silvio Gesell, who wrote an article about the experiment.[36]
1890s and early 1900s
[edit]The application of deliberate demurrage rates on currency was first theorized to have economic benefits by Silvio Gesell in the 1890s. Gesell first started thinking about the structural problems caused by the monetary system after the 1890 depression in Argentina hurt his business considerably. Gesell released his first theoretical writing on currency: The Reformation of the Monetary System as a Bridge to a Social State (German: Die Reformation des Münzwesens als Brücke zum sozialen Staat, 1891). He also wrote and published The Nerve of Things (Latin: Nervus rerum, 1891) and The nationalization of money (German: Die Verstaatlichung des Geldes, 1892). In 1916, Gesell later published his most famous work on demurrage, The Natural Economic Order.
After Gesell died in 1930, many localities were inspired his economic theories and tried using demurrage currencies to alleviate their local economies during the Great Depression.
The Great Depression
[edit]
Demurrage-charged local currency was tested in the Austrian town of Wörgl between 1932 and 1934, as a tax collected for the benefit of the unemployed. Despite the local currency's success in reducing unemployment and increasing economic activity, Austria's central bank Oesterreichische Nationalbank outlawed complimentary currencies in the country on 1 September 1933, so that the federal government would maintain a monopoly on the country's currency and legal tender.[37][38]
Local stamp scrip systems, many of which incorporated demurrage fees, were used in many towns during the Great Depression in the United States. Most scrip was issued in late 1932 and early 1933 before FDR succeeded the presidency, and when bank suspensions were the most frequent and widespread. The New Jersey, Ohio, Michigan, Indiana, North Dakota, Tennessee, and North Carolina state legislatures all passed laws allowing localities in their respective states to issue stamp scrip.[39][40] Iowa even went as far as to propose issuing statewide stamp scrip, but never enacted it.[41] Oregon planned to print $80 million of stamp scrip in 1933, but was stopped by the U.S. Treasury.[15] The experiments became so popular that the economist Irving Fisher decided to analyze them. Fisher recommended issuing dated stamp scrip nationwide in his book Stamp Scrip, but US President Franklin Delano Roosevelt rejected Fisher's recommendations.[42][23]
Fisher composed the Bankhead-Pettengill bill that was introduced to Congress by Senator John H. Bankhead II of Alabama on February 17, 1933. Fisher proposed a nationwide issue of up to $1 billion in $1 dated stamp scrip as legal tender under the US Treasury, but the bill never came to a vote. Similar bills were subsequently proposed in Congress, but none succeeded.[39] In March 1933, President Franklin Roosevelt banned all further issues of stamp scrip out of fear that the federal government would lose its authority over the monetary system.,[43]: 7 [2]: 12 which arguably prolonged the Great Depression.[citation needed]
In 1933, a National Committee of the Mutual Exchanges was formed in Nice, France, which created trade vouchers intended to circulate only between members, mainly traders. (The Committee's statutes appeared in the press on 12 September, the creation of the association being officially announced at the Olympic Day on 10 December of the same year). Under the Ministry of Laval, the Banque de France intervened and declared the experiment as illegal. After World War II, jeweler by the name of Soriano, who participated in this experiment, gave his support for "the libre commune of Lignières-en-Berry".[44][45]
In 1936, the Social Credit Party-led government in Alberta, Canada, introduced prosperity certificates in an attempt to alleviate the effects of the Great Depression, with holders having to affix to the back of a certificate a 1-cent stamp before the end of every week, for the certificate to maintain its validity.
In August 1936, the city of Montoro issued what might have been the first demurrage currency in all of Spain. The local council printed a series of five-peseta bills, each with a depreciation table on one side. The value of bills decreased weekly. For example, a bill that was worth five pesetas on November 1 would be worth 4.50 pesetas on November 8. If the bills remained unused after twelve weeks, they would be only partially redeemable at the town hall. Similar monetary experiments also took place in Porcuna and other locations in Spain that were ruled by the Popular Front in Córdoba province in 1936-1937.[2]: 15
At the end of the Spanish Civil War, Francisco Franco's government confiscated and voided all Republican money, municipal coins, and local banknotes. Meanwhile, Franco decreed that all the municipal currencies issued by the winning national army could be exchanged at the Bank of Spain for the new Spanish currency (Order 5, Decree 27 August 1938 published on 17 September 1938). Despite being prohibited, many complementary currencies continued to circulate among the population as a medium of exchange for years after the Spanish Civil War (1939-1955).[2]: 15
Post World War II
[edit]The major central banks' post-World War II policy of steady monetary inflation as proposed by Keynes was influenced by Gesell's idea of demurrage currency,[21] but used inflation of the money supply rather than fees to increase the velocity of money in an attempt to expand the economy.
On 9 September 1950, the Free Social Party was founded in Germany with a platform based on Gesell's Freiwirtschaft theory. After a few name changes, it has been known as the Human Economics Party (German: Humanwirtschaftspartei) since 28 April 2001.[46]
Two brief experiments took place in Cher in 1956 and Charente-Maritime in 1957 respectively. Issued by an association under the term "vouchers" or "work vouchers", these demurrage currencies were abandoned in December 1958 following the adoption of an ordinance prohibiting "the issuance or putting into circulation of means of payment intended to replace or replace legal tender signs".[47]
Pierre Tournadre, a watchmaker, and Georges Lardeau, director of a cinema, who faced rural exodus and economic decline, declared on 26 April 1956 "the libre commune of Lignières-en-Berry". The demurrage money was issued in August 1956. As word of the experiment spread, the government started tabling a bill in December to try to ban the currencies. In June 1957, a judicial police investigation pressed no charges. The journal "Science et Vie" (Étienne Dugue, La monnaie accelerated, number 488, May 1958) noted that this experiment ended on 24 December 1958, due to the passage of ordinance 58-1298.[48][44]
The Great Recession
[edit]The Great Recession inspired many communities to establish local demurrage currencies. There are currently a handful of demurrage currencies that are still used today.[49]
In, Shaymuratovo, Bashkortostan, Russia, the town's declining agricultural enterprise implemented a demurrage currency in 2010, in the wake of the Great Recession. The government believed that this was a violation of labor laws and shut the currency down. The community tried to implement a demurrage currency once more, but this time as gift cards, instead of an official currency. People were paid their full salaries and rubles, but then could buy the new currency in the company stores and then buy goods with it. Overall, the experiment caused commodity turnover to increased dramatically. Productivity increased, arrears were paid off, and salaries increased. The surrounding region took notice and other businesses started to accept the currency, whether from the experiment or from the business climate improving in general. Although the goal of saving the business was achieved and the economy was stabilized, the government once again tried to stop the experiment multiple times, leading to its retirement after a few years.[50][51]
List of demurrage currencies
[edit]Current currencies
[edit]- Chiemgauer, a community currency in Bavaria, Germany, started in 2003.
- Stroud pound, a community currency in Stroud, Gloucestershire, England, started in 2009.[49]
- Occitan, a community currency in Languedoc-Roussillon, France, started in 2010.
- Abeille, a community currency in Villeneuve-sur-Lot, France, started in 2010.
- Freicoin, a crypto-currency.
- Palai, a crypto-currency.
- Ergo, a crypto-currency.
- Circles, a crypto-currency.
Defunct currencies
[edit]- Wära, a local currency used in Schwanenkirchen, Germany and later other cities as one of the first free economy experiments. It was introduced by Hans Timm and Helmut Rödiger, who were followers of Silvio Gesell. It was introduced in 1926, and operated until it was shut down by the German Central Bank and the Reich Ministry of Finance.
- Wörgler Schwundgeld , the currency of the Wörgl Experiment. Began on 31 July 1932 and ended by Austria's central bank Oesterreichische Nationalbank on 1 September 1933.[37][38]
- Local currency "stamp scrip" experiments were conducted in several cities in the United States during the 1930s.[41][40][39] In March 1933, President Franklin Roosevelt banned all further issues of stamp scrip out of fear that the federal government would lose its authority over the monetary system.,[43]: 7 [2]: 12 which arguably prolonged the Great Depression.[citation needed]
- Prosperity certificate, a local currency in Alberta, Canada that existed in 1936.[52]
- WIR Bank, a bank founded by Swiss businessmen Werner Zimmermann and Paul Enz that circulated demurrage currency from 1936 to 1948.[53]
- Crédito, an Argentine local currency, started on 1 May 1995 that became defunct in the 2000s. Allegedly, the Argentinian "barter clubs" in the late 1990s and the early-2000s were perhaps the most widely used demurrage currency in modern history. At its peak, millions of people participated in the barter clubs.[citation needed]
- E-gold, a demurrage private currency where there was a gold storage charge of 1% per annum. The demurrage associated with e-gold is arguably expended by the currency operator to help cover real storage costs.[citation needed] E-gold was launched in 1996, and suspended in 2009 due to legal issues.
- Renovatio Monetae was a monetary system during the High Middle Ages where coins had to be called back and exchanged for new coins regularly, about once or twice a year.[28][27]
- In Ancient Egypt, ostraka – dated receipts for the storage of grain – functioned as a demurrage currency.[28]
Proposed currencies
[edit]- A carry tax on currency was proposed by a Federal Reserve employee (Marvin Goodfriend) in 1999, to be implemented via magnetic strips on bills, deducting the carry tax upon deposit, the tax being based on how long the bill had been held.[54]
- Bernard Lietaer's terra is a commodity basket currency proposal similar to Keynes's bancor or L'Europa (The idea to establish a L'Europa – monnaie de la paix from early concepts presented in an article in the French newspaper Le Fédériste on 1 January 1933) and bearing a demurrage charge.[citation needed]
Fictional currencies
[edit]- Michael Ende stated that he had the concept of demurrage currency in mind when writing his children's fantasy novel Momo.[55] Momo features a currency that revolves around time, which can be exchanged between people.
- A negative interest rate could be levied on existing paper currency in principle via a serial number lottery, such as randomly choosing a number 0 through 9 and declaring that notes whose serial number end in that digit are worthless, yielding an average 10% loss of paper cash holdings to hoarders; a drawn two-digit number could match the last two digits on the note for a 1% loss. This was proposed by an anonymous student of Greg Mankiw,[56] though it was more of a thought experiment than a genuine proposal.
See also
[edit]Notes
[edit]- ^ The etymology for demurrage currency comes from the concept of demurrage. In the shipping industry, "demurrage" refers to a charge that is assessed to the operator of a ship that fails to load or unload within the agreed upon timeframe. A ship that takes longer than it's supposed to unload to load or unload affects the ability of other ships to do likewise. Therefore a financial penalty is assessed to discourage such behavior. Demurrage money applies the same principle, but to money.[1]
- ^ a b In other contexts, demurrage may refer to the carrying cost associated with owning or holding currency over a given period, rather than the money itself. For commodity money such as spices, demurrage is the cost of storing and securing the spices. For paper currency, it can take the form of a periodic tax, such as a stamp tax, on currency holdings.
References
[edit]- ^ Sidman, Josh (3 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #6 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 6:47. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ a b c d e f g h Gomez, Georgina M; Prittwitz und Gaffron, Wilko von (2018). "The pervasiveness of monetary plurality in economic crisis and wars" (PDF). Erasmus University Rotterdam. International Institute of Social Studies of Erasmus University Rotterdam. Retrieved 25 April 2025.
- ^ a b c Rosalsky, Greg (27 August 2019). "The 'Strange, Unduly Neglected Prophet'". NPR. Retrieved 25 April 2025.
- ^ Gesell, Silvio (1916). "Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld" [The Natural Economic Order/Part III/Chapter 10: The Supply of Money]. Translated by Pye, Philip. Bern, Switzerland. ISBN 9781610330442. Archived from the original on 17 March 2025. Retrieved 30 April 2025 – via The Anarchist Library.
{{cite web}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ a b Gesell, Silvio (1916). "Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld" [The Natural Economic Order/Part IV/Chapter 1: Free-Money]. Translated by Pye, Philip. Bern, Switzerland. ISBN 9781610330442. Archived from the original on 17 March 2025. Retrieved 30 April 2025 – via The Anarchist Library.
{{cite web}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ Gesell, Silvio (1916). "Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld" [The Natural Economic Order/Part IV/Free-Money, Or Money As It Should Be]. Translated by Pye, Philip. Bern, Switzerland. ISBN 9781610330442. Archived from the original on 17 March 2025. Retrieved 30 April 2025 – via The Anarchist Library.
{{cite web}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ Sidman, Josh (4 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #2 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 29:00. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Smith, Fred J. (2015). Quantum Money. CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform. ISBN 978-1517264048.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (3 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #6 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 9:56. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ Bozhya-Volya, Roman N.; Rybak, Alina S. (18 January 2019). "Why Should Money Lose Value With Time: Boosting Economy in the Era of E-Money" (PDF). Higher School of Economics. National Research University Higher School of Economics. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ Stock, James H.; Watson, Mark W. (February 2007). "Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to Forecast?" (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 39 (1). Blackwell Publishing Limited. Retrieved 2 May 2025 – via Harvard University.
- ^ Bill Mitchell, MMT & Inflation, 2010
- ^ Bershidsky, Leonid (3 July 2015). "'Neglected Prophet' of Economics Got It Right". Bloomberg. Retrieved 1 June 2017.
- ^ Shen, Lucinda (2016-02-23). "Japan's Negative Interest Rates Are Driving up Sales of Safes". Fortune. Retrieved 1 June 2017.
- ^ a b c d e f Baynham, Jacob (14 November 2023). "What If Money Expired?". Noema Magazine. Berggruen Institute. Retrieved 26 April 2025.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (25 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #5 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Bernard Lietaer: transaction.net Community Currencies: A New Tool for the 21st Century.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (25 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #5 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 44:41. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (11 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #3 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 16:32. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Fuders, Felix (April 2023). How to Fulfill the UN Sustainability Goals: Rethinking the Role and Concept of Money in the Light of Sustainability. Cham, Switzerland: Springer Nature Switzerland AG. ISBN 978-3-031-37767-9. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ a b Keynes, John Maynard (February 1936). "Book 6, Chapter 23: Notes on Mercantilism, The Usury Laws, Stamped Money and Theories Of Under-Consumption". The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan. ISBN 978-0-230-00476-4. Retrieved 17 April 2025 – via Freie Universität Berlin.
{{cite book}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ Sidman, Josh (10 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #7 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 35:22. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ a b "Depreciating currencies: The money-go-round". The Economist. 22 January 2009. Archived from the original on 26 April 2025. Retrieved 8 February 2018.
- ^ Läufer, Nikolaus (31 December 2006). "Natural Economic Order Theories or Freiwirtschaftslehre (Silvio Gesell)" (in German). University of Konstanz. Archived from the original on 20 November 2012. Retrieved 3 April 2014.
- ^ Altvater, Elmar. "Eine andere Welt mit welchem Geld?" [Another world with what money?] (PDF). Freie Universität Berlin. Retrieved 27 April 2025.
- ^ Onken, Werner (31 December 2004). "Für eine andere Welt mit einem anderen Geld – Sind die Geldreformer wirklich Antisemiten?" [For another world with another money: Are the money reformers really anti-Semites?]. Freie Universität Berlin. Retrieved 27 April 2025.
- ^ a b Svensson, Roger (April 2013). Renovatio Monetae: Bracteates and Coinage Policies in Medieval Europe. Stockholm, Sweden: DeckersSnoeck, Belgium. ISBN 978-1-907427-29-9.
- ^ a b c Lietaer, Bernard A. (2000). Mysterium Geld. Emotionale Bedeutung und Wirkungsweise eines Tabus [Mystery of Money]. Riemann Verlag. ISBN 978-3570500095.
- ^ Décobert, C. (1991), Le mendiant et le combattant, L’institution de l’islam, Paris: Éditions du Seuil, pp. 238–240.
- ^ Medani Ahmed and Sebastian Gianci, Zakat, Encyclopedia of Taxation and Tax Policy, p. 479, quote: "As one of the Islam's five pillars, zakat becomes an obligation due when, over a lunar year, one controls a combination of income and wealth equal to or above Nisaab."
- ^ Sarwar, Muhammad (2015). al-Kafi Volume 1 of 8 (2nd ed.). New York: The Islamic Seminary Inc. p. 345. ISBN 978-0-9914308-6-4.
- ^ a b Yusuf al-Qaradawi (1999), Monzer Kahf (transl.), Fiqh az-Zakat, Dar al Taqwa, London, Volume 1, ISBN 978-967-5062-766, p. xix.
- ^ Marty, Martin E. & Appleby, R. Scott (1996). Fundamentalisms and the state: remaking polities, economies, and militance. University of Chicago Press. p. 320. ISBN 978-0-226-50884-9.
- ^ Samiul Hasan (2015). Human Security and Philanthropy: Islamic Perspectives and Muslim Majority Country Practices. Springer. p. 130. ISBN 978-1493925254.
- ^ Benjes, Hermann (2003). "Das Mirakel von Guernsey" [The Miracles of Guernsey] (PDF) (sixth ed.). ISBN 3-00-000204-9. Archived from the original (PDF) on 8 December 2015. Retrieved 11 May 2025.
- ^ Gesell, Silvio (1922). Die Guernsey-Markthalle. In: Die Freiwirtschaft durch Freiland und Freigeld [The Guernsey Market Hall. The free economy through free land and free money]. Silvio Gesell: Gesammelte Werke, Gauke Verlag für Sozialökonomie. Vol. 14. Kiel, Germany.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) - ^ a b Boyle, David (2002). The Money Changers: Currency Reform from Aristotle to E-cash. Earthscan. ISBN 978-1-85383-895-8.
- ^ a b Helleiner, Eric; Helleiner, Faculty of Arts Chair in International Political Economy Professor Eric (2003). The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-0-8014-4049-6.
- ^ a b c Champ, Bruce (April 2008). "Stamp Scrip: Money People Paid To Use" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Research Department. Retrieved 21 April 2025.
- ^ a b Wolfgang Broer: Schwundgeld: Bürgermeister Michael Unterguggenberger und das Wörgler Währungsexperiment 1932/33, 2007, p. 323, ISBN 3706544725, 9783706544726.
- ^ a b Warner, Jonathan (2012). "Iowa Stamp Scrip: Economic Experimentation in Iowa Communities during the Great Depression". University of Iowa. The State Historical Society of Iowa. Retrieved 21 April 2025.
- ^ Fisher, Irving (1933). Stamp Scrip. New York. Retrieved 18 April 2025.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) - ^ a b Lietaer, Bernard A. (July 1990). "A Strategy for a Convertible Currency" (PDF). ICIS Forum. 20 (3). International Center for Integrative Studies. Retrieved 4 May 2025.
- ^ a b Catherine Célimène et Guy Deffeyes, 1995, Le Nouveau Pari monnaie-terre; voyage au pays de l'art de dissoudre le chômage et quelques autres préjugés…, janvier 1995, éditions Terre Active
- ^ Laacher Smaïn. L'État et les systèmes d'échanges locaux (SEL). Tensions et intentions à propos des notions de solidarité et d'intérêt général. In: Politix, vol. 11, n°42, Deuxième trimestre 1998. Définir l'intérêt général, sous la direction de Brigitte Gaïti, Arthur Jobert et Jérôme Valluy. pp. 123-149
- ^ "Grundsatzprogramm der Humanwirtschaftspartei" [Basic program of the Human Economy Party]. Archived from the original on 8 December 2015.
- ^ Ferreira, Nathalie. « De la réforme du système monétaire à la monnaie sociale : l’apport théorique de P.J. Proudhon (1809-1865). » L'Actualité économique, volume 86, numéro 2, juin 2010, p. 205–225.
- ^ https://www.lanouvellerepublique.fr/actu/la-lignieres-pour-dynamiser-l-economie-locale
- ^ a b Town launches its own bank notes BBC News 13 September 2009
- ^ Hasslberger, Sepp (5 February 2013). "Bashkir farmers' local demurrage currency recognized by Supreme Court". Sepp Hasslberger. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ Money: Shaimurots in Shaimuratovo
- ^ Charlton Standard Catalogue of Canadian Government Paper Money, ISSN 1716-0731, 18th edition, p. 13. Charlton Press.
- ^ Studer, Tobias (1998). WIR and the Swiss National Economy. WIR Bank, Basel. p. 59.
- ^ McCullagh, Declan (27 October 1999). "Cash and the 'Carry Tax'". WIRED. Retrieved 2011-12-21.
- ^ Michael Ende's last words to the Japanese Archived 2006-10-10 at the Wayback Machine.
- ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (18 April 2009). "It May Be Time for the Fed to Go Negative". The New York Times.
External links
[edit]- Taxonomy of money systems, with discussion of relationship of demurrage concept to others
- T.H. Greco. "Money: understanding and creating alternatives to legal tender". White River Junction, Vt: Chelsea Green Publishing, 2001.
- Bernard Lietaer. The Future of Money. Century; New Ed edition (February 1, 2002) ISBN 0-7126-9991-0
- Lietaer, Bernard A. (2001). The future of money: a new way to create wealth, work, and a wiser world. London: Century. ISBN 0-7126-9991-0.
- Freicoin
- F. Smith, N. Penchev, Quantum Money (2015) ISBN 978-1517264048.